Financial Database


Global Financial Data: Offers extensive free historical data and research as well as information on extensive historical database which includes data on stock markets, inflation rates, interest rates and exchange rates going back to the 1600s.

Factiva: Global news and business information service that combines the content sets of Dow Jones Interactive and Reuters Business Briefing. Covers real time news from 8,000 worldwide publications, news pictures and company financials. [Intranet] Quick Guide Demo
Bloomberg: The leading provider of data, news and analytics globally. The Bloomberg Terminal (Library Level 2) and Bloomberg’s media services provide real-time and archived financial and market data, pricing, trading, news and communications tools in a single, integrated package to corporations, news organizations, financial, legal professionals and individuals around the world.
MoneyScience Financial Intelligence Network: an open access resource for academics and practitioners working in Quantitative Finance, Economics, Applied Mathematics and Physics.

JEROME L. STEIN Biographical Sketch (2008)

Stein, Jerome L. Born Nov. 14, 1928, Brooklyn New York. B.A. Brooklyn College summa cum laude 1949, M.A. Yale University 1950, Ph.D. Yale University 1955; Docteur Honris Causa, Université de la Méditerranée, Aix Marseille II France 1997.

Married Hadassah Levow August 1950. Children. Seth, William Deering Professor Geological Sciences, Northwestern University, Evanston Illinois; Gil, Director Oriental Institute University of Chicago; Ilana Ben-Ze’ev, partner law firm, Bodman LLP Michigan.

Joined Department of Economics Brown University 1953. Professor of Economics 1962 - 93, Eastman Professor Political Economy, Brown University 1970 - 93. Emeritus 1993; Visiting Professor/Research Division Applied Mathematics, DAM Brown University, 1997 - present.

Visiting professor: Hebrew University, Jerusalem Israel 1965-66, 1972-73; Ford Foundation research professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley 1979-80; Sorbonne Paris, Paris 1982; Tohoku University, Tohoku Japan 1983, Fellow Japan Society for the Advancement of Science; Haute Études Commerciale HEC France, 1987; Monash University, University of Melbourne, Australia 1989; University Bordeaux IV, France 1990; Université de la Méditerranée, Aix Marseille II France, 1992, 1995 – 1998; La Spienza, University Rome, Italy, 1994. University Munich CESifo 1994.

Economic Growth in a Free Market (with G. H. Borts), Columbia University Press 1964; Money and Capacity Growth, , Columbia, University Press 1971; Monetarist, Keynesian and New Classical Economics, Blackwell, 1982; Monetarism, North Holland, 1976; Economics of Futures markets, Blackwell, 1986; Fundamental Determinants of Exchange Rates, Oxford University Press, 1995; Stochastic Optimal Control, International Finance and Debt Crises, Oxford University Press, 2006.

Honors

Ford Foundation Faculty Fellowship 1961-62; Social Science Research Council Faculty Fellowship 1965-66; John Simon Guggenheim Fellowship 1972-73; National Science Foundation Grants ; Ford Foundation Grants Fellow of Japan Society for the Promotion of Science 1983; Docteur Honoris Causa, l’Université de la Méditerranée Aix- Marseille II 1997. Keynote Speaker international conferences concerning optimization: EUROPT-2007, Prague, EUROPT-2008, Lithuania.

Professional acivities

Associate Editor, Journal of Finance, Director, International Finance, American Finance Association 1965-70; Board of Editors, American Economic Review, 1974-80; Associate Editor, Journal of International and Comparative Economics. Associate Editor, Journal of Banking and Finance (JBF), Editor special issues: "Real and Nominal Exchange Rates.", JBF (1997); Intertemporal Optimization in a Stochastic Environment" JBF (2007); Editor, special issue of Australian Economic Papers (AEP), "Stochastic Models in Economics and Finance", (2005); "Exchange Rates in Europe and Australasia" AEP (2002); Economic Record, "Futures Markets.".

Consultant: Department of Commerce, 1972; National Science Foundation, site; visitor; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 1973, 1976; International Monetary Fund, 1994; European Central Bank, 1999; Social Science Research Council Faculty Research Grants Committee 1969-72; Chairman 1971-72.

Research Interests

My main research interest is interdisciplinary modeling between applied mathematics and important economic problems. Fruitful collaboration with Ettore Infante (DAM) to economic growth, fiscal policy and stabilization policy 1969 – 80, and with Wendell H. Fleming (DAM) 1997 – present using stochastic optimal control and dynamic programming to international finance. Currently I am applying it to the mortgage crisis 2007 – 2008.

International Finance

NATREX model of the equilibrium real exchange attracted attention of central banks: Banque de France, Deutsche Bundesbank, European Central Bank, Czech National Bank, Central Bank of Hungary, Eastern European central banks, Central banksLatin American countries who applied it to their real exchange rates.

Stochastic Optimal Control

This is interdisciplinary research, with Wendell Fleming of DAM, applying the state of art techniques in stochastic optimal control to important economic problems. They are primarily the recent debt crises, including the mortgage debt crisis. Invited speaker/keynote: American Mathematical Society, World Congress Nonlinear Analysis, European Society for Optimization (EUROPT) conferences in Prague (2007), Lithuania (2008). Main resulting publication is Stochastic Optimal Control, International Finance and Debt Crises, Oxford University Press, 2006.

NATREX

NATREX stands for NATural Real EXchange rate. It attempts to give a fair value for a currency. It is part of the family of long run equilibrium exchange rate theories (FEER, BEER, and NATREX). Notably the The approach offers an alternative paradigm to the Purchasing Power Parity for equilibrium real exchange rates.

Natrex can be compared to PPP (Purchasing Power Parity) type methods. These are based mainly on an analysis of the goods and services market. However the NATREX also integrates capital flows as long-term determining factors for exchange rates. This makes it easier to consider NATREX as a real equilibrium exchange rate.

Stein*/ (2006) has offered the clearest definition of the NATREX-based view of the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate: The equilibrium value of the real exchange rate NATREX is a sustainable rate that satisfies several criteria. First; it is consistent with internal balance. This is a situation where the rate of capacity utilization is at its longer run stationary mean. Second, it is consistent with external balance. The latter is a situation where, at the given exchange rate, investors are indifferent between holding domestic or foreign assets. At the equilibrium real exchange rate, there is no reason for the exchange rate to appreciate or depreciate. Hence, portfolio balance or external balance implies that real interest rates between the two countries should converge to a stationary mean. As long as there are current account deficits, the foreign debt and associated interest payments rise. If the current account deficit/foreign debt exceeds the growth rate of real GDP, then the ratio of the debt/GDP and the burden of the debt - net interest payments/GDP - will rise. When the debt burden is sufficiently high, devaluation will be required to earn enough foreign exchange through the trade balance to meet the interest payments. The condition for external equilibrium in the longer run is that the ratio of the foreign debt/GDP stabilizes at a tolerable level.

The NATREX is not constant but varies with "fundamentals" Z(t)which are relative productivity and relative "thrift", which is the ratio of relative consumption/GDP ratios. The actual equilibrium real exchange rate converges to the moving "equilibrium" NATREX. The convergence can occur either through variations in the nominal exchange rate or in relative prices.

Schematically the real exchange rate R(t) at any time is a sum involving three terms. R(t) = [R(t) - R[F(t);Z(t)] + [R(F(t);Z(t)] - R[Z(t)] + R[Z(t)].

The medium run equilibrium is R[F(t), Z(t)] where the debt F(t) is given and the real fundamentals Z(t) are given. The long run equilibrium is R[Z(t)] where the debt has converged to its equilibrium value. In the medium run the NATREX exchange rate converges to R[F(t);Z(t)]. In the longer run the debt adjusts and the medium run NATREX converges to R[Z(t)] the longer run NATREX which just depends upon the real fundamentals Z(t) = {relative productivity, relative consumption ratios}. The difference {R(t) - R[F(t);Z(t)]} between the actual real exchange rate and the medium run NATREX results from speculative random behavior and from cyclical factors. In the medium to the longer run, these disturbances have zero means. Thus the NATREX is where the real exchange rate is heading along a trajectory. The PPP model is a special case where the NATREX is constant, and the PPP ignores the NATREX stock-flow dynamics.

In the standard models, an expansionary fiscal policy appreciates the real exchange rate. In NATREX, the expansionary fiscal policy appreciates the medium run NATREX. However, due to the induced accumulation of external debt, the long run NATREX depreciates below its initial level. On the other hands a rise in relative productivity appreciates the medium run NATREX and the long run NATREX appreciates even more.

The underlying techniques of analysis are vector matrix differential equations, and stochastic optimal control/dynamic programming – since the intertemporal optimization is based upon stochastic processes where the future is unpredictable. The analysis is used to explain the debt crises.

It has been applied to the $US/Euro, the currencies of the Transition Economies in Eastern Europe, Australia, China and to the Latin American currencies by researchers, Central banks and the International Monetary Fund.

Technical Discussion of Equilibrium Exchange Rates, NATREX and Misalignment

An equilibrium exchange rate is where the exchange rate is heading. The concept and measure of the equilibrium exchange rate depends upon the time horizon and the underlying model. Several reasons have been cited in the literature , why it is important to estimate equilibrium exchange rates. First, there are significant and sustained movements in exchange rates. These movements affect the competitiveness of the economies and their macroeconomic stability. One wants to know whether these movements are ephemeral or whether they are responding to "real fundamentals" . This information is important because the answer has implications for rational macroeconomic policy and for rational investment decisions. If the depreciation of an exchange rate is due to a depreciation of its equilibrium value, then exchange market intervention or a restrictive monetary policy designed to offset the depreciation is counterproductive.

Second, in the case of monetary unions such as the Euro area, it is important to know how a potential entrant should select its exchange rate. An "overvalued" rate will depress growth and produce problems such as beset the eastern part of Germany. An "undervalued" rate will generate inflationary pressures. The measure of "over-valuation" and "under-valuation" must contain an explicit measure of an "equilibrium" real exchange rate.

Our emphasis is upon the equilibrium real exchange rate. It is defined as the nominal exchange rate times relative prices. In an adjustable peg regime, the nominal exchange rate is fixed and the actual real exchange rate varies due to changes in relative prices. In a floating exchange rate regime, both the nominal exchange rate and relative prices can lead to adjustments in the actual real rate. The only difference from our point of view is that the adjustment of the actual real exchange rate to the equilibrium will be faster when the exchange rate floats, because the nominal exchange rate is more flexible than relative prices.

A widely used approach in the literature is to "explain" the exchange rate by the uncovered interest rate parity theory (UIRP) . It states that the anticipated appreciation of the exchange rate is equal to the anticipated interest rate differentials over a period of a given length. There are several limitations of this approach. First: the UIRP equation concerns the change in the exchange rate but does not contain any information concerning where the exchange rate is heading. As Driver and West away state, the exchange rate at any given time t will jump around to adjust to any change in either the anticipated exchange rate at some future date t+h or any change in anticipated interest rate differentials over the interval (t, t+h). The UIRP theory per se has no anchor.

Second: for the theory to have significance one must tie down the anchors. One anchor must be the "equilibrium" exchange rate and the second must be the path of the interest rates. This is not done in the UIRP theory. Third: the theory states that the interest rate differential at time t is a good and unbiased predictor of the subsequent change in the exchange rate. The "tests" of the theory generally relate ex-post changes in the exchange rate to the previous interest rate differentials. In general, the results of these tests are not encouraging. The interest rate differential has the incorrect sign and is unsuccessful in predicting exchange rate movements.

For these reasons, authors who are interested in explaining exchange rates focus upon the anchor, the equilibrium exchange rate - where the exchange rate is heading. Then the theory of UIRP has structure. The actual exchange rate at time t is equal to the present value of the equilibrium exchange rate, where the discount factor is the interest rate differential. There are two types of candidates for the equilibrium exchange rate. One is Purchasing Power Parity (PPP), which assumes that the equilibrium real exchange rate is a constant. As mentioned above, this hypothesis is unimpressive as an explanation of the anchor.

The other candidate is an equilibrium real exchange rate that depends upon time varying real, measurable "fundamentals" . This has led to the literature of " equilibrium exchange rates", which was given great impetus by John Williamson's influential book (1994). The logic of this approach goes back to Ragnar Nurske's article. The "equilibrium" exchange rate is the exchange rate that is associated with both external and internal balance. Anticipations, speculative capital movements and changes in reserves are excluded from the concept of an equilibrium exchange rate, which is where the exchange rate is heading. The NATREX model of equilibrium exchange rates generalizes the work of Williamson and Nurske. It is a Neoclassical growth model, whose underlying equations are based upon intertemporal optimization by the private sector, but not the government whose decisions are political.

The NATREX explains the fundamental determinants of the medium run equilibrium and the dynamic trajectory to the long run equilibrium. In the medium run equilibrium there are both internal and external balance. In both the medium run and longer run the NATREX equilibrium real exchange rate satisfies equation (1), subject to constraints. The constraints are that there is internal balance, where the rate of capacity utilization is at its longer term mean, and external balance where the real rates of interest at home and abroad are equal, there are neither changes in reserves, nor speculative capital flows based upon anticipations. The equilibrium real exchange rate is the mean of a distribution, which is based upon real fundamentals. The mean will vary over time due to endogenous changes in capital and external debt, as well as changes in the exogenous real fundamentals. Deviations from this mean are produced by speculative factors involving anticipations, by cyclical factors, lags in adjustment, and interest rate differentials. These disequilibrium elements average out to zero. These deviations produce considerable variation but their effects are ephemeral.

The terms in square brackets are that investment investment less saving [I(t) - S(t)] plus the current account is equal to zero. The current account [B(t )- r(t)F(t)] is the trade balance B(t) less transfers of interest and dividends rtFt. The net external debt is F(t) and r(t) is the "interest/dividend" rate. The international investment position consists of equity, portfolio investment and direct investment. The debt F(t) is the negative of the net international investment position. Measure investment, saving and the debt as fractions of the GDP.

(1) [I(t) - S(t)] + [B(t) - r(t)F(t)] = 0

All of the authors who take the equilibrium real exchange rate approach use equation (1) to determine the exchange rate. The main differences among them concern their treatment of the two terms. Some work with a concept of what is a "sustainable" current account such that the debt does not "explode". As is discussed in Stein (2006) chapter 9 on the United States current account deficits, their estimates are subjective, so their equilibrium exchange rate is a "normative" concept. The NATREX approach is quite different in several respects, primarily because the endogenous current account generates an evolving external debt, which feeds back into the medium run equation (1). A trajectory to longer run equilibrium is generated. The other difference is that the underlying equations are derived from inter-temporal optimization by the private sector.

The dynamics of the debt/GDP ratio F(t) is equation (2), where g is the growth rate. The current account deficit is the change in the external debt. The real exchange rate affects the trade balance B in equation (1), and the trade balance affects the evolution of the actual debt ratio in equation (2). There is a dynamic interaction between the endogenous real exchange rate and debt ratio.

(2)dF(t)/dt = (I(t) - S(t)) - g(t)F(t) = [r(t)F(t) - B(t)] - g(t)F(t)] = (r(t)-g(t)F(t) - B(t)

In longer run equilibrium, the debt ratio stabilizes at F*(t) at a value that satisfies equation (3). The trade balance B(t) is sufficient to finance the interest plus dividend transfer on the debt net of growth [r(t) - g(t)]F(t) and the exchange rate at and the exchange rate at R*(t). A negative debt is net foreign assets.

(3) [r(t)-g(t)]F(t)- B(t) = 0.

The longer-run equilibrium real exchange rate R(t)* and debt/GDP ratio F(t)* are endogenous variables that satisfy both equations (1) and (3). They are written as (4) and (5) to indicate that they both depend upon the real fundamentals Z(t).

(4) R(t)* = R(Z(t)) (5) F(t)* = F(Zt))

We call dynamic stock-flow model equations (1) - (3) the NATREX model, which is an acronym for the Natural Real Exchange Rate . This is a model of positive economics. The literature associated with Williamson's FEER uses equation (1) and does not contain the dynamic interactions, equations (2) and (3). The NATREX model derives the private saving, private investment and trade balance equations from optimization criteria. There is no presumption that the government saving and investment decisions are optimal, since they are based upon political considerations not upon social welfare.

Populist and Growth Scenarios

The NATREX model is a technique of analysis. The purpose of the model is to understand the effects of policies and external disturbances upon the trajectories of the equilibrium real exchange rate R(t) and equilibrium debt ratio F(t), which depend upon the vector of fundamentals Z(t). Insofar as the fundamentals vary over time, the equilibrium real exchange rate and debt ratio will vary over time, as indicated in equations (4) and (5). The logic and insights of the NATREX model can be summarized in two scenarios. Each scenario concerns different elements in the vector Z(t) of the fundamentals, and has different effects upon the equilibrium trajectories of the real exchange rate NATREX and of the external debt. NATREX analysis concerns the equilibrium real exchange rate and it is neither the actual real exchange rate nor the optimal exchange rate that would lead to the optimal debt ratio.

The first scenario, called the Populist scenario, involves a decline in the ratio of social saving/GDP. This could occur when the government incurs high-employment budget deficits, lowers tax rates that raise consumption, or offers loan guarantees/subsidies for projects with low social returns. This represents rise in the consumption ratio/a decline in the saving ratio, a shift in the S function in equations (1) and (2). These Populist expenditures are designed to raise the standards of consumption/quality of life for the present generation.

The second scenario, called the Growth scenario, involves policies designed to raise the productivity of capital. Policies that come to mind involve the liberalization of the economy, increased competition, wage and price flexibility, the deregulation of financial markets, improved intermediation process between savers and investors, and an honest and objective judicial system that enforces contracts. Growth policies improve the allocation of resources and bring the economy closer to the boundary of an expanding production possibility curve.

Table 1 summarizes the differences between the two scenarios in the medium and the long run. The stories behind the dynamics are as follows.

The Populist scenario involves increases in social (public plus private) consumption relative to the GDP. External borrowing must finance the difference between investment and saving. The capital inflow appreciates the real exchange rate from initial level R(0) to medium run equilibrium R(1), where T = 1 denotes medium run equilibrium. The current account deficit is balanced by the capital inflow. The debt rises, since the current account deficit is the rate of change of the debt - equation (2). Current account deficits lead to growing transfer payments rtFt. This Populist scenario is potentially dynamically unstable because the increased debt raises the current account deficit, which then increases the debt further. The exchange rate depreciates, and the debt rises, steadily.

Stability can only occur if the rise in the debt, which lowers net worth equal to capital less debt, reduces social consumption/raises social saving. For example, the growing debt and depreciating exchange rate force the government to decrease the high employment budget deficit. Thereby, saving less investment rises. Long-run equilibrium (denoted by T = 2) is reached at a higher debt F(2) > F(0) and a depreciated real exchange rate R(2) <>

 

NATREX dynamics of exchange rate and external debt: Two Basic Scenarios Scenarios R = real exchange rate (rise is appreciation), F = external debt/GDP; initial period T = 0, medium run T=1, long-run T=2.

Medium-run, T = 1 Longer-run T = 2

Populist: Rise in social in social consumption (discount rate, time preference), rise in high employment government budget deficit, decline social saving

R(1) > R(0) appreciation Debt rises F(1) > F(0) R(2) <> F(1) > F(0)

Growth oriented: Rise in productivity of investment, expansion of production possibility set. Rise in growth, rise in competitiveness appreciation R(1) > R(0) Debt rises F(1) > F(0) appreciation R(2) > R(1) > R(0) Debt declines F(2) <>

The Growth scenario is summarized in the lower half of table 1. The perturbation is a rise in the productivity of investment and an expansion of the production possibility set. Investment rises because of the rise in the rate of return. The difference between investment and saving is financed by a capital inflow. The exchange rate appreciates to R(1) > R(0) which reduces the trade balance and produces a current account deficit. The initial current account deficit equal to [I(0) - S(0)] raises the debt. The trade deficit provides the resources to finance capital formation, which raises the growth rate and the competitiveness of the economy.

It does not matter much where the rise in the return on investment occurred or what factors led to an expansion of the production possibility set. If they are in the traditional export or import competing sectors, the trade balance function B = B(R;Z) increases. The B function, which relates the real value of the trade balance to the real exchange rate R, increases with a rise in the overall productivity of the economy. For example, the reallocation of resources leads to the production of higher quality/value goods that can compete in the world market. If the rate of return on investment and productivity increase in the sectors that are not highly involved in international trade, resources can then be released for use in the more traditional "tradable" sectors. Again, the B function supply curve increases.

The trajectory to longer-run equilibrium differs from that in the Populist scenario. The crucial aspect implied by the Growth Scenario is that, at medium run equilibrium exchange rate R(1), the trade balance function increases. The real exchange rate appreciates and there are now current account surpluses, excess of saving over investment. As a result, the debt then declines to a new equilibrium F(2) <> R(1) > R(0). The external debt reaches a maximum and then declines to F(2) <>

EURO Linguistic issues

The formal titles of the currency are "euro" for the major unit and "cent" for the minor (one hundredth) unit and for official use in most Eurozone languages; according to the ECB, all languages should use the same spelling for the nominative singular. This may contradict normal rules for word formation in some languages, e.g. those where there is no eu diphthong. For English texts the European Commission's Directorate-General for Translation recommends that the plural forms 'euros' and 'cents' should be used when appropriate. 


EURO Exchange rates

U.S. dollars per 1 euro 1999-2009

Year    Lowest ↓                Highest ↑

            Date      Rate        Date     Rate

1999    03 Dec   $1.0015    05 Jan    $1.1790

2000    26 Oct   $0.8252    06 Jan    $1.0388

2001    06 Jul     $0.8384    05 Jan    $0.9545

2002    28 Jan    $0.8578    31 Dec  $1.0487

2003    08 Jan    $1.0377    31 Dec  $1.2630

2004    14 May  $1.1802    28 Dec  $1.3633

2005    15 Nov  $1.1667    03 Jan    $1.3507

2006    02 Jan    $1.1826    05 Dec  $1.3331

2007    12 Jan    $1.2893    27 Nov  $1.4874

2008    27 Oct   $1.2460    15 Jul     $1.5990

2009    05 Mar   $1.2555    02 Jan    $1.3866

Source: Euro exchange rates in USD, ECB

 

Flexible exchange rates

The ECB targets interest rates rather than exchange rates and in general does not intervene on the foreign exchange rate markets, because of the implications of the Mundell-Fleming Model which suggest that a central bank cannot maintain interest rate and exchange rate targets simultaneously because increasing the money supply results in a depreciation of the currency. In the years following the Single European Act, the EU has liberalised its capital markets, and as the ECB has chosen monetary autonomy, the exchange rate regime of the euro is flexible, or floating. This explains why the exchange rate of the euro vis-à-vis other currencies is characterised by strong fluctuations. Most notable are the fluctuations of the euro versus the U.S. dollar, another free-floating currency. However this focus on the dollar-euro parity is partly subjective. It is taken as a reference because the euro competes with the dollar's role as reserve currency. The effect of this selective reference is misleading, as it gives observers the impression that a rise in the value of the euro versus the dollar is the effect of increased global strength of the euro, while it may be the effect of an intrinsic weakening of the dollar itself.

Against other major currencies

Exchange rate evolution of the euro compared to USD, JPY and GBP. Exchange rate at start is put to 1.
After the introduction of the euro, its exchange rate against other currencies fell heavily, especially against the U.S. dollar. From an introduction at US$1.18/€, the euro fell to a low of $0.8228/€ by 26 October 2000. After the appearance of the coins and notes on 1 January 2002 and the replacement of all national currencies, the euro then began steadily appreciating, and soon regained parity with the U.S. dollar, on 15 July 2002. Since December 2002, the euro has not again fallen below parity with the U.S. dollar but instead began ascendancy. On 23 May 2003, the euro surpassed its initial ($1.18) trading value for the first time. At the end of 2004, it reached $1.3668 (€0.7316/$) as the U.S. dollar fell against all major currencies. Against the U.S. dollar, the euro temporarily weakened in 2005, falling to $1.18 (€0.85/$) in July 2005, and was stable throughout the third quarter of 2005. In November 2005 the euro again began to rise steadily against the U.S. dollar, hitting one record high after another. On 15 July 2008, the euro rose to an all-time high of $1.5990 (€0.6254/$). In a reversal, in August 2008 the euro began to drop against the U.S. dollar. In just two weeks the euro fell from its peak to $1.48 and by late October it reached a two and a half year low below $1.25. On 29 December 2008, the pound sterling fell to an all-time low of £0.97855 (€1.0219/£) against the euro.

 

Currencies pegged to the euro

Worldwide use of the euro and the U.S. dollar: Eurozone External adopters of the euro Currencies pegged to the euro Currencies pegged to the euro within narrow band United States External adopters of the US dollar Currencies pegged to the US dollar Currencies pegged to the US dollar within narrow band

Several non-EU currencies that were pegged to a European currency are now pegged to the euro: the Cape Verdean escudo, the Bosnia and Herzegovina convertible mark, the CFP franc, the CFA franc and the Comorian franc.

In total, the euro is the official currency in 16 countries inside the European Union, and 5 countries/territories outside the European Union. Several other EU members will ultimately join the euro. In addition, 23 states and territories have currencies that are directly pegged to the euro including 14 countries in mainland Africa, 2 African island countries, 3 French Pacific territories and another Balkan country, Bosnia and Herzegovina.

Though the United Kingdom is not in the Eurozone, many high-street banks report that as much as 90% of their international trade is conducted in euro. It is common therefore for them to use the euro as their 'core' currency on international business systems, only converting to Sterling for local accountancy purposes.

Euro Economics

Optimal currency area

In economics, an optimum currency area (or region) (OCA, or OCR) is a geographical region in which it would maximize economic efficiency to have the entire region share a single currency. There are two models, both proposed by Robert A. Mundell: the stationary expectations model and the international risk sharing model. Mundell himself advocates the international risk sharing model and thus concludes in favour of the euro.

Transaction costs and risks

The most obvious benefit of adopting a single currency is to remove the cost of exchanging currency, theoretically allowing businesses and individuals to consummate previously unprofitable trades. For consumers, banks in the Eurozone must charge the same for intra-member cross-border transactions as purely domestic transactions for electronic payments (e.g. credit cards, debit cards and cash machine withdrawals).

The absence of distinct currencies also removes exchange rate risks. The risk of unanticipated exchange rate movement has always added an additional risk or uncertainty for companies or individuals that invest or trade outside their own currency zones. Companies that hedge against this risk will no longer need to shoulder this additional cost. This is particularly important for countries whose currencies have traditionally fluctuated a great deal, particularly the Mediterranean nations.

Financial markets on the continent are expected to be far more liquid and flexible than they were in the past. The reduction in cross-border transaction costs will allow larger banking firms to provide a wider array of banking services that can compete across and beyond the Eurozone.

Price parity

Another effect of the common European currency is that differences in prices—in particular in price levels—should decrease because of the 'law of one price'. Differences in prices can trigger arbitrage, i.e. speculative trade in a commodity across borders purely to exploit the price differential. Therefore, prices on commonly traded goods are likely to converge, causing inflation in some regions and deflation in others during the transition. Some evidence of this has been observed in specific markets.

Macroeconomic stability

Low levels of inflation are the hallmark of stable and modern economies. Because a high level of inflation acts as a tax (seigniorage) and theoretically discourages investment, it is generally viewed as undesirable. In spite of the downside, many countries have been unable or unwilling to deal with serious inflationary pressures. Some countries have successfully contained them by establishing largely independent central banks. One such bank was the Bundesbank in Germany; as the European Central Bank is modelled on the Bundesbank, it is independent of the pressures of national governments and has a mandate to keep inflationary pressures lowMember countries that join the bank commit to lower inflation, hoping to enjoy the macroeconomic stability associated with low levels of expected inflation. The ECB (unlike the Federal Reserve in the United States of America) does not have a second objective to sustain growth and employment.

Many national and corporate bonds denominated in euro are significantly more liquid and have lower interest rates than was historically the case when denominated in legacy currencies. While increased liquidity may lower the nominal interest rate on the bond, denominating the bond in a currency with low levels of inflation arguably plays a much larger role. A credible commitment to low levels of inflation and a stable debt reduces the risk that the value of the debt will be eroded by higher levels of inflation or default in the future, allowing debt to be issued at a lower nominal interest rate.

Euro Usage

The euro is the sole currency of 16 EU member states: Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia and Spain. These countries comprise the "Eurozone" or "Euro Area", some 326 million people in total.

With all but two of the remaining EU members obliged to join, together with future members of the EU, the enlargement of the eurozone is set to continue further. Outside the EU, the euro is also the sole currency of two former Yugoslavian states (Montenegro and Kosovo) and several European micro states (Andorra, Monaco, San Marino and Vatican).

It is also gaining increasing international usage as a trading currency, in Cuba, North Korea and Syria. Since its introduction, the euro has been the second most widely-held international reserve currency after the U.S. dollar. The euro inherited this status from the German mark, and since its introduction, it has increased its standing, mostly at the expense of the dollar. The increase of 4.4% in 2002 is due to the introduction of euro banknotes and coins in January 2002.

The possibility of the euro's becoming the first international reserve currency is now widely debated among economists. Former Federal Chairman Alan Greenspan gave his opinion in September 2007 that the euro could indeed replace the U.S. dollar as the world's primary reserve currency. He said it is "absolutely conceivable that the euro will replace the dollar as reserve currency, or will be traded as an equally important reserve currency." 

The introduction of the euro

Preceding national currencies of the Eurozone  

Currency                    Code       Rate                 Fixed on             Yielded  

Austrian schilling           ATS          13.7603        31 Dec 1998           2002

Belgian franc                 BEF          40.3399        31 Dec 1998            2002

Dutch guilder                NLG          2.20371        31 Dec 1998            2002

Finnish markka             FIM          5.94573        31 Dec 1998           2002

French franc                 FRF          6.55957        31 Dec 1998            2002

German mark                DEM          1.95583        31 Dec 1998          2002

Irish pound                   IEP          0.787564      31 Dec 1998           2002

Italian lira                      ITL          1,936.27       31 Dec 1998           2002

Luxembourgian franc     LUF          40.3399        31 Dec 1998       2002

Portuguese escudo        PTE          200.482        31 Dec 1998         2002

Spanish peseta              ESP          166.386        31 Dec 1998          2002

Greek drachma             GRD          340.750        19 June 2000      2002

Slovenian tolar              SIT          239.640        11 July 2006        2007

Cypriot pound              CYP          0.585274      10 July 2007         2008

Maltese lira                   MTL          0.429300      10 July 2007        2008

Slovak koruna              SKK          30.1260        8 July 2008           2009

The euro was established by the provisions in the 1992Maastricht Treaty. In order to participate in the currency, member states are meant to meet strict criteria such as abudget deficit of less than three per cent of their GDP, a debt ratio of less than sixty per cent of GDP, low inflation, and interest rates close to the EU average. In the Maastricht Treaty, the United Kingdom and Denmark were granted exemptions per their request from moving to the stage of monetary union which would result in the introduction of the euro.

Economists who helped create or contributed to the euro include Robert Mundell, Wim Duisenberg, Robert Tollison, Neil Dowling, Fred Arditti and Tommaso Padoa-Schioppa. The name eurowas devised on 4 August 1995 by Germain Pirlot, a Belgian Esperantist and ex-teacher of French and history, and officially adopted in Madrid on 16 December 1995.

 Due to differences in national conventions for rounding and significant digits, all conversion between the national currencies had to be carried out using the process of triangulation via the euro. The definitive values in euro of these subdivisions (which represent the exchange rates at which the currency entered the euro) are shown at right.

The rates were determined by the Council of the European Union, based on a recommendation from the European Commission based on the market rates on 31 December 1998. They were set so that one European Currency Unit (ECU) would equal one euro. The European Currency Unit was an accounting unit used by the EU, based on the currencies of the member states; it was not a currency in its own right. They could not be set earlier, because the ECU depended on the closing exchange rate of the non-euro currencies (principally the pound sterling) that day.

The procedure used to fix the irrevocable conversion rate between the drachma and the euro was different, since the euro by then was already two years old. While the conversion rates for the initial eleven currencies were determined only hours before the euro was introduced, the conversion rate for the Greek drachma was fixed several months beforehand.

The currency was introduced in non-physical form (travellers' cheques, electronic transfers, banking, etc.) at midnight on 1 January 1999, when the national currencies of participating countries (the Eurozone) ceased to exist independently. Their exchange rates were locked at fixed rates against each other, effectively making them mere non-decimal subdivisions of the euro. The euro thus became the successor to the European Currency Unit (ECU). The notes and coins for the old currencies, however, continued to be used as legal tender until new euro notes and coins were introduced on 1 January 2002.

The changeover period during which the former currencies' notes and coins were exchanged for those of the euro lasted about two months, until 28 February 2002. The official date on which the national currencies ceased to be legal tender varied from member state to member state. The earliest date was in Germany where the mark officially ceased to be legal tender on 31 December 2001, though the exchange period lasted for two months more. Even after the old currencies ceased to be legal tender, they continued to be accepted by national central banks for periods ranging from several years to forever. The latter being the case in Austria, Germany, Ireland, and Spain. The earliest coins to become non-convertible were the Portuguese escudos, which ceased to have monetary value after 31 December 2002, although banknotes remain exchangeable until 2022.